The next enlargement of the European Union with ten Candidate Countries
may bring a major transformation of the Union.(1) In this essay, we look
at the consequences of the accession of these countries on EU trade policy.
More specifically, we assess whether this enlargement could lead the Union
to behave more like a protectionist regional bloc, as some fear. This
political-science analysis(2) deals with this question through two interrelated
issues.
Firstly, the possible influence on the European position in the multilateral
trading system is looked at. Here the question of trade diversion and
conformity with GATT Article XXIV(3) is inevitably raised, as the WTO
is concerned about the impact of regional trade agreements on the multilateral
trading system. After each previous enlargement, negotiations for compensation
agreements with WTO members affected by enlargement have taken place.(4)
Such being the case, claims for compensation under Article XXIV could
be expected after the next enlargement. The US has already announced a
WTO negotiation with the EU over the trade effects of enlargement, once
enlargement actually takes place (Wayne 2002). However, we would put the
danger of trade diversion and subsequent compensation claims into perspective.
· Unlike previous enlargements, many of the conditions for liberal
trade in industrial products will already be established prior to accession.
By 2002 one can speak of a pan-European framework for commercial interaction
(Kaminski 2000; Brenton 1999). As trade diversion costs are likely to
be low, problems of trade compensation under WTO rules are not expected
(Rollo 1995; Johnson and Rollo 2001).
· Trade diversion in agricultural trade may be more difficult to
avoid, as the general level of protection in eastern Europe is lower than
the current CET. Important agricultural countries such as Hungary and
Poland are less protectionist than the EU in external agricultural protection.
So the Union is likely to raise border protection in new member countries,
causing trade diversion. Hungary was until recently a member of the liberal
Cairns group of agricultural exporters, but had to withdraw in '99 at
the demand of the EU (Tovias 2001). Estonia has already had to abandon
its very liberal trade regime raising agricultural tariffs to conform
to EU requirements, so the EU will have to compensate Estonia's trading
partners (Kaminski 2000). However, also regarding agriculture, Swinnen
(2002) states that accession is less likely to create a conflict with
WTO commitments than initially feared.
· CCs will probably be less enthusiastic about multilateral services
liberalization. However, as this is the EU's major offensive interest
in the WTO and there is a consensus among current member states about
this issue, it seems very unlikely that CCs will be able to exercise much
influence here (van den Hoven 2002).
In addition, the EU and the CCs have already anticipated demands for compensation.
As a CC representative made clear, the main concern of CCs during their
negotiations with the WTO was to avoid opening their markets more than
the EU. Furthermore, it was suggested that negotiations on such claims
are more a question of a political struggle for power than of economic
analysis. Threats about compensations may form a bargaining tool of trading
partners in other issues, such as the Doha Development Agenda or transatlantic
trade disputes (steel, gmo's etc.). In this context it is interesting
to know that the vagueness of GATT Article XXIV (FTAs should cover 'substantially
all trade' and must not 'on the whole' be more restrictive than previously)
makes broad interpretations possible (Frandsen, Jensen and Vanzetti 2000).
It is clear that most CCs (with the exception of Estonia and the Czech
Republic) have preferred bilateral and regional to multilateral foreign
trade liberalisation. Falling tariff rates on industrial imports from
preferential partners have not spilled over to MFN policy. (Kaminski 2000)
But on the other hand, all acceding countries became WTO members, subjected
to the rules of the multilateral trading system. Both their discourse(5)
and their policy indicate that regionalism and multilateralism are probably
complementary, although the easier option of regional integration has
been given priority. This seems to be a reflection of the traditional
European balance between regionalism and multilateralism.
Moreover, the increased economic size of the Union will probably increase
internal and external pressures for a worldwide commitment of the EU in
the economic field. The fact that the Union has intensified its economic
relations with Russia and the FSU countries does not preclude a more global
role of the EU, as recent initiatives in Latin America (Mexico, Chile,
Mercosur) and the Everything but Arms-initiative indicate. The Union also
seems to be the main supporter of a new WTO round. Contrary to the declining
power of the US, the EU's interests are increasingly promoted by multilateral
trade liberalization. So developing(6) and developed countries' fears
for 'attention diversion' (Bergsten 1997) are probably premature.
Secondly, the question presents itself whether enlargement will shift
the balance to a more or less liberal (free-trade-oriented) Europe. Already
from the start of the EC, a simplifying distinction between a group liberal-trading
northerners (led by Germany and the Netherlands) and a more protectionist
southern group (led by France and Italy) can be made. (Johnson and Rollo
2001) Not surprisingly, each enlargement has shifted the balance to a
more liberal (with the UK, Scandinavian countries and Austria) or a more
protectionist (with the Mediterranean members) EU trade policy (Grabbe
and Hughes 1998). What is the position of the CCs on the protectionist
- liberal spectrum?
Since the beginning of the 1990s, the CCs' trade policies have undergone
a major transformation. In spite of differences between them and temporary
setbacks, they all moved swiftly from an institutional design of central
planning and a strong bias against foreign trade, to a market-based trade
regime in most industrial and agricultural goods. Trade flows were largely
redirected from the former Soviet Union towards the EU(7). Apart from
"systemic change" (the end of communism), the "EU factor"
became the most powerful liberalising force. After the '89 revolutions
the Union quickly extended GSP status to its eastern neighbours and between
'91 and '95 it concluded Association Agreements with all CEECs. The "core"
of these 'Europe Agreements' consisted of trade provisions, leading to
a standstill of existing tariff levels and the gradual reduction of tariffs
and quantitative restrictions on trade (Hare 2001). Moreover, contrary
to what one might expect considering previous trade liberalisation in
developed countries, the rapid fall in tariffs was not followed by an
increase in non-tariff barriers (Kaminski 1999). Most CCs have much lower
trade barriers than did Spain and Portugal at the time of their entry
into the EU and they are certainly much less protectionist than Austria
and Finland were on agriculture until 1995. (Johnson and Rollo 2001) All
respondents to our questionnaire indicated that trade in goods and services
should be further liberalised within the WTO.
Summarizing, it should be emphasized that "a surprisingly liberal
trade regime is now in place in the Central and Eastern European countries
seeking EU accession" (Hare 2001). The EBRD and Michalopoulos (1999)
give the eight acceding CEECs the highest ranking regarding liberalisation
of their trade system.(8)
However, despite the CC's free trade inclination, a few remarks on potential
protectionist tendencies should be noticed. First of all, new members
might take advantage of existing EU instruments for anti-dumping to protect
their more vulnerable industrial sectors (such as chemicals, iron and
steel). There is a precedent here: the accession of Austria, Sweden and
Finland instigated some anti-dumping measures that did not apply in these
countries previously. (Frandsen, Jensen and Vanzetti 2000) Secondly, the
expected boost to agriculture could shift the relatively liberal countries
towards the agricultural protectionist camp within the EU. (Johnson and
Rollo 2001; van de Hoven 2002)
More generally, one could question whether the acceding countries will
stay on the liberal track once they have joined the Union. While the ongoing
liberalization of foreign trade during the 1990s should to a large extent
be ascribed to the 'EU factor' (see above), most countries (with the exception
of Estonia: Purju 1996) are characterized by the absence of pro-free trade
lobbies and domestic pro-protection sentiments prevail. Ill-designed institutional
foundations, bureaucratic temptation to micromanage tariffs and an apparent
lack of political support for free trade among elite and populace at large
(Kaminski 2000) might eventually shift the balance to a rather protectionist
policy within the EU. Lithuania's former Ambassador to the EU confirms
that his country's "relatively liberal" trade regime has come
under pressure from "influential interest groups" (Cicinskas,
Cornelius and Treigiene 1996), and Latvian civil servants describe the
protective inclination of the bureaucracy and the weakness of consumer
organizations (Shteinbuka and Cirule 1996).
Although these comments should be borne in mind, we consider a volte-face
away from the CC's current liberal trade policy very unlikely. After all,
the ongoing process of Europeanization will probably continue to play
an important 'socializing' role in the policy new member states.(9)
Finally, apart from the new members' preferences in trade policy, their
formal and actual influence will probably be relatively small. How much
will their decision-making powers in European trade policy amount to?
Even if all acceding states took a protectionist stance, there is no arithmetical
prospect that they could link with the existing more protectionist group
to achieve the necessary votes that will be needed to bring about a standing
protectionist majority (Johnson and Rollo 2001; Tovias 2001). Hanson observed
that, after the completion of the single market, the institutional setting
of EU trade policy-making advances external liberalization. So also after
enlargement, a minority of free-trade-oriented member states can always
block protectionist measures and "erecting new trade barriers of
any kind would be difficult without great consensus among member states"
(Hanson 1998). Of course this argument does not apply for trade issues
(such as audio-visual services as well as education, health care and public
services) were member states still have a veto power according to the
Nice Treaty. However, these issues may be less problematic than sometimes
suggested (Rollo and Holmes).(10) Since 1995 Central and Eastern European
Countries have supported the EU position in WTO negotiations (van den
Hoven 2002). During all EU-CC accession negotiations Chapter 26 on external
relations has been closed without insurmountable difficulties.
Claims that enlargement constitutes a kind of non-tariff barrier because
EU trade policy decision-making would become even more complicated (Senti
2002) are not necessarily true. If the number of participants at the decision-making
process increases, the Commission can more easily appoint itself as a
mediator between the member states - even on issues that strictly speaking
do not belong to its competences (Kerremans 1996). More generally, the
importance of the number of actors for providing a collective good could
be questioned. Strömvik (2000) shows that, although there may be
a 'pure numbers effect' and some kind of 'threshold logic', there are
other countervailing forces as well.
In addition to this analysis on the 'systemic' level of decision-making
(Peterson and Bomberg 1999), during the first years of membership the
CCs actual influence may be diminished because of their limited integration
in the 'sub-systemic' policy networks (Peterson and Jones 1999). The Europe
Agreements provide for multilateral dialogue and 'structured relationship'
to bring the CCs closer to EU institutions and the process of decision-making.
Regular informal (de)briefings on trade policy are organised by DG Trade
on the level of Ambassadors or senior diplomats. Moreover, ministerial
conferences with the EU and the CCs on WTO and Trade issues have been
organised yearly since November 1999.(11)
But it remains to be seen whether CCs are ready to participate fully in
the policy-making and operational activities of the article 133 Committee,
including the informal exchanges that surround its formal work.(12) Peterson
and Jones are also rather pessimistic about the integration of new member
states at this level, as they lack technocratic expertise, access to resources
(such as information, funding and legitimacy) and coalition-building skills.
"If the most recent enlargement is any guide, we should expect officials
and lobbyists from eastern applicant states to remain outgunned at the
sub-systemic level long after accession. In particular, the time lag between
accession and recruitment of eastern nationals to the Commission means
they will remain under-represented at the centre of EU policy networks
until well into the twenty-first century. (Peterson and Jones 1999)"
One official from a CC confirmed that they have scarcely been involved
with the informal networks of EU decision-making.(13)
From this short overview of the 'multilateralism versus regionalism' and
the 'liberalism versus protectionism' debates, it remains an open question
whether eastern enlargement will entail a 'Fortress Europe'. However,
we are inclined to conclude that, notwithstanding the critical remarks
we made, fears for a more protectionist and inward-looking Europe should
not be exaggerated. During the past decade CEECs have shown an unprecedented
move towards trade liberalisation and integration in the world trading
system. To the extent that Europe might become a protectionist regional
bloc, this will be attributable to other factors (e.g. economic recession;
US protectionism; 'anti-globalism' and growing politization of trade policy
etc.) than to EU enlargement.
* Research Assistant of the Fund for Scientific Research - Flanders.
Department of Political Science, Faculty of Political and Social Sciences,
Ghent University (Belgium).
NOTES
1) We use the term (European) Union (EU), also if strictly speaking it
concerns the European Community. The term Candidate Country (CC) refers
to the ten countries that are most probably acceding to the EU in 2004
(Poland, Hungary, Czech Republic, Slovakia, Slovenia, Estonia, Latvia,
Lithuania, Cyprus and Malta), excluding Bulgaria, Romania and Turkey.
2) The essay is based on literature and a few questionnaires and interviews
with representatives of the CCs to the EU (April-May 2002).
3) GATT Article XXIV (5) 5 states that duties and other regulations of
commerce "shall not be higher or more restrictive than the corresponding
duties and other regulations of commerce existing in the same constituent
territories prior to the formation of the free-trade area"; The GATS
treaty (article V) has less strict conditions.
4) For example, the enlargement with Spain in 1986 was followed by a trade
row between the EU and the United States over the amount of compensation.
After threats of retaliation and counter retaliation, both sides eventually
compromised. The 1995 enlargement (with Austria, Sweden and Finland) also
led to compensation negotiations with the United States, Canada, Australia,
and other trading partners that claimed trade loss. In December '95 the
EU finally offered compensation acceptable to the other parties. (Ginsberg
1998)
5) E.g. Latvia's former Ambassador to the EU talks about a "multi-route
approach of bilateral, regional and global integration". (Cicinskas,
Cornelius and Treigiene 1996)
6) Here we will not elaborate on the consequences of enlargement for developing
countries (among which the ACP). Recent initiatives (Doha Development
Round, Monterrey, the new GSP, Cotonou and the ongoing EPA negotiations,
Everything but Arms) indicate, however, that there is not simply a 'zero-sum
game' between tge EU relations with Eastern Europe and those with the
South.
7) However, in '94 a free trade area among Central and Eastern European
countries (CEFTA) and a trilateral free trade agreement among the Baltic
countries entered into force.
8) Estonia, Latvia and the Czech Republic have the most liberal trade
regimes. The two CEECs that are not acceding in 2004, Bulgaria and Romania,
are considered as the least liberal countries (Tsoukalis 1997).
9) For an application of this argument on the effects of enlargement on
European Common Foreign and Security Policy, see: Sjursen 1998; Stromvik
2000.
10) It should also be noted that in practice, as a consequence of several
mechanisms (such as its information advantage, the impact of globalisation
etc.) the Commission plays a more important role in trade policy than
formal provisions suggest (Kerremans 1996).
11) The latest ministerial meeting took place in Malta from (31 May -
1 June 2002).
12) "The formal debates in the Committee are shadowed by a constant
process of bilateral discussion, ad hoc alliances between member states,
telephone and e-mail exchanges, and visits to capitals." (Johnson
and Rollo 2001b).
13) They have only been involved in a few working groups and advisory
committees of the Commission, but not those involving financial and political
issues. They have not been allowed at working groups or committees under
the European Parliament or the Council of Ministers. Of course their participation
at this sub-systemic level may be enhanced after signing the Act of Accession.
REFERENCES
BERGSTEN, Fred C. (1997), Open Regionalism. In: The World Economy, 5,
pp.545-565.
BRENTON, Paul (1999), Anti-Dumping, Diversion and the Next Enlargement
of the EU. Brussels, Centre for European Policy Studies, Working Document
No. 129, March 1999, 17p.
CICINSKAS, Jonas, CORNELIUS, Peter K., TREIGIENE, Dalia (1996), Trade
Policies and Lithuania's Reintegration into the Global Economy. Stockholm,
Stockholm Institute of East European Economies, Working Paper No. 111,
April 1996, 48p.
FRANDSEN, S.E., JENSEN, H.G., VANZETTI, D.M. (2000), Expanding 'Fortress
Europe': Agricultural Trade and Welfare Implications of European Enlargement
for Non-member Regions. In: World Economy, 23, 3, pp.309-329.
GINSBERG, Roy H. (1998), The Impact of Enlargement on the Role of the
European Union in the World. In: REDMOND, John, ROSENTHAL, Glenda G.,
(eds.), The expanding European Union: past, present, future. Colorado,
Lynne Rienner Publishers, pp.197-216.
GRABBE, Heather, HUGHES, Kirsty (1998), The Impact of Enlargement on EU
Trade and Industrial Policy. In: REDMOND, John, ROSENTHAL, Glenda G.,
(eds.), The expanding European Union: past, present, future. Colorado,
Lynne Rienner Publishers, pp.125-156.
HANSON, Brian T. (1998), What Happened to Fortress Europe? External Trade
Policy Liberalization in the European Union. In: International Organization,
52, 1, pp.55-85.
HARE, Paul (2001), Trade Policy During the Transition: Lessons from the
1990s. In: World Economy, 2001, pp.483-511.
JOHNSON, Michael, ROLLO, Jim (2001a), EU Enlargement and the Making of
Commercial Policy. Brighton, Sussex European Institute, Briefing Paper
No 6., 3p.
JOHNSON, Michael, ROLLO, Jim (2001b), EU Enlargement and Commercial Policy:
Enlargement and the Making of Commercial Policy. Brighton, Sussex European
Institute, Working Paper No 43, March 2001, 28p.
KAMINSKI, B. (1999), The EU Factor in Trade Policies of Central European
Countries. Washington, DC, World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper 2239.
KAMINSKI, B. (1999), How Accession to the European Union Has Affected
External Trade and Foreign Direct Investment in Central European Economies.
Revised version of a background paper prepared for the 'Prague 2000 Accession'
session at the IMF/World Bank annual meeting held in Prague, September
2000, 42p.
KERREMANS, Bart, Besluitvorming en integratie in de externe economische
betrekkingen van de Europese Unie. België, Universa Press, 1996,
243p.
MICHALAPOLOUS, Constantine (1999), The Integration of Transition Economies
into the World Trading System. Washington, DC, World Bank, Working Paper
2182.
PETERSON, John, JONES, Peter, Decision making in an enlarging European
Union. In: SPERLING, James, (ed.), Europe in Change: Two tiers or two
speeds? Manchester, Manchester University Press, 1999, pp.25-45.
PETERSON, John, BOMBERG (1999), Elizabeth, Decision-making in the European
Union. Houndmills, Macmillan, 336p.
PURJU, Alari (1996), Foreign Trade of Estonia: Factors Supporting Integration.
Stockholm, Stockholm Institute of East European Economies, Working Paper
No. 113, July 1996, 51p.
ROLLO, Jim (1995), EU enlargement and the world trade system. In: European
Economic Review, 39, pp.467-473.
ROLLO, Jim, HOLMES, Peter, EU Commercial Policy after Nice. Sussex European
Institute, SEI Briefing Paper No 3, 3p.
SENTI, Richard (2002), The Role of the EU as an Economic Actor within
the WTO. In: European Foreign Affairs Review, 7, pp.111-117.
SHTEINBUKA, Inna, CIRULE, Aleksandra (1996), Foreign Trade in Latvia:
On the Way to EU Membership. Stockholm, Stockholm Institute of East European
Economies, Working Paper No. 115, October 1996, 62p.
SJURSEN, Helene (1998), Enlargement and the Common Foreign and Security
Policy: Transforming the EU's External Policy? Arena Working Papers, WP
98/18, http://www.arena.uio.no/publications/wp98_18.htm.
STROMVIK, Maria (2000), Do Numbers Matter? The EU's Common Foreign and
Security Policy and the Dynamic Effects of Enlargement. Sweden, Centre
for European Studies (Lund University), 28p.
SWINNEN, Johan (2002), Transition and Integration in Europe: Implications
for Agricultural and Food Markets, Policy, and Trade Agreements. In: World
Economy, pp.481-501.
TOVIAS, Alfred (2001), On the External Relations of the EU21: The Case
of the Mediterranean Periphery. In: European Foreign Affairs Review, 6,
autumn 2001, pp.375-394.
TSOUKALIS, Loukas (1997), The New European Economy revisited. Oxford,
Oxford University Press, 306p.
VAN DEN HOVEN, Adrian (2002), Enlargement and the EU's Common Commercial
Policy. Paper presented at the Bigger and Better? The European Union,
Enlargement and Reform - ECSA-C Conference (30 May - 1 June 2002), Toronto,
Canada.
WAYNE, Anthony, Enlargement and Transatlantic Economic Relations. Remarks
by Assistant Secretary of State for Economic and Business Affairs, Paul
H. Nitze School of Advanced International Studies, Washington, DC, 22
October 2001.
|