Recent debates about globalization among decision makers and social scientists
have coined the term "pathfinders of globalization" (Harss and
Maier, 1998). A good segment of the international social scientific community
would be in accordance with such a role-description, while an equally
important and growing segment of the social scientific community would
vehemently oppose the basic axioms of globalization in its present form.
Conventional wisdom of the "Washington Consensus" has it that
it is always the periphery or semi-periphery country that got it all wrong
during a crisis, like in East Asia, Russia or recently in Turkey and that
a good combination of economic freedom, privatization, tight monetary
policies and above all private foreign direct investment will "fix"
it, once the forces of the market are properly at work.
The "Washington Consensus" has been summarized by Raffer (pp.
305 - 323 in Tausch, 2003) as to represent the following policy priorities:
1. Fiscal discipline: a primary budget surplus of several percent of
GDP
2. Public expenditure priorities: defined as re-directions of public expenditures
towards fields with high economic returns such as primary health and education
3. Tax reform: cutting marginal tax rates
4. Financial liberalization: moderately positive real interest rates and
the abolition of preferential interest rates (such as for developmentally
useful or socially demanded projects)
5. Exchange rates: unified and competitive
6. Trade liberalization: abolishing quotas (replacing them by tariffs)
and reducing tariffs to a uniform low level within three to ten years.
7. Foreign direct investment: equal treatment with domestic firms. The
World Bank calls this the elimination of barriers. This principle is also
enshrined in the WTO treaties
8. Privatization
9. Deregulation: abolishing regulations aiming at achieving developmental
or social aims
10. Property rights: must be guaranteed
The counter-position, advanced by globalization critics, environmentalists,
liberation theologians of all denominations, and - most recently - dissidents
from the once homogeneous neo-liberal camp would hold that unfettered
globalization increases the social gaps between rich and poor both within
countries as well as on a global scale. Most of the adherents of this
camp would share the view proposed by Cornia and Kiiski that income distribution
in the world system has worsened during the period of globalization.
The idea that economic and social progress is not linear has many implications
for the ascent and decline of nations in the world system. The clearest
proof of discontinuous development in our age is the real income at purchasing
power data series available from the international developmental institutions.
Large parts of our globe were once richer, in real terms, than in 2000;
a great number of countries experienced real decades of economic impoverishment
over the last 1/4 of a Century. The UNDP 2002 electronic data base easily
permits such a calculation from 1975 to 2000. The UNDP data tell you in
which year since 1975 the highest income was reached. Normally, you would
expect that a country had 25 years of progress since 1975, but this is
not the case. Many nations reached their maximum national average welfare
in the 1980s, several of them even before. When you subtract from the
number 2000 the year with the highest real income since 1975, you arrive
at a global map of development failure since 1975, and you arrive equally
at a map of the failures of globalization since 1975. 63 nations lost
10 or more years of their development; and only 70 of 159 ranked countries
had their highest average real welfare level in 2000. The record holders
of development failure in these terms (20 or more years lost) were the
following 26 countries: (Angola, Bolivia, Central African Republic, Chad,
Côte d'Ivoire, El Salvador, Gabon, Ghana, Guatemala, Haiti, Honduras,
Iran, Jamaica, Kuwait, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritania, Namibia, Nicaragua,
Niger, Nigeria, Saudi Arabia, Senegal, Togo, Venezuela, Zambia).
The Latin American social scientist Osvaldo Sunkel first proposed in his
essay 'Transnational capitalism and national disintegration (in Latin
America)' the still provocative thought that transnational investment
and integration might go hand in hand under certain conditions with an
increasing relative social polarization between rich and poor in the host
countries of the evolving transnational system and on the international
level. While debates abound, hard-core social scientific evidence on the
contradictory effects of globalization is needed more than ever before.
The Intense Debate about Globalization and Social Welfare in the World
System
On the surface, there seems to exist a certain kind of agreement among
the political and the research community world wide that globalization
since 1980 negatively affected the lives of around 1.5 thousand million
people on earth, whose per-capita incomes were lower than in earlier decades.
These 1.5 thousand million people live in around 100 countries; while
15 nations experienced rapid capitalist development over the last decade
(UNDP, 1996, 1997).
No question that the world economy is characterized at present, as happened
in earlier periods, by a quantitative and qualitative jump in the degree
of globalization (Arrighi and Silver, 1999; Boswell and Chase-Dunn, 2000;
Cornia and Kiiski, 2001). Luttwak defines this present phase as 'turbo
capitalism' by private enterprise, liberated from government regulation,
unchecked by effective trade unions, unfettered by concerns for employees
or communities, and unhindered by taxation or investment restrictions.
Globalization is generally understood to be the growing transborder flow
of goods, services, capital and labor. The following UNDP 2000 numbers
might illustrate this:
* World exports are more than 21% of world GNP
* Foreign direct investments are above 400 thousand million $
* Daily currency exchanges are 1500 thousand million $, i.e. the annual
world currency trade is 18.6 times the yearly world GNP
* International bank credits are above 4200 thousand million $
Summarizing the unique UNCTAD World Investment Report 2002 data base,
freely available on the Internet, one is lead to the following conclusions:
1. there was a tremendous increase in the process of globalization in
the 1990s, but
2. this process experienced a sharp decline in its growth rate already
prior to the 09/11 attacks in New York, indicating a qualitative and quantitative
reversal in the capitalist world economy.
Both inward and outward investments increased tremendously until the
year 2000, and declined sharply in 2001. Also the value of cross-border
mergers and acquisitions declined sharply in that year.
At the same time, it has been established fairly well enough that there
is a continuing phenomenon of world poverty. But what beyond that? Is
globalization really the cause of world poverty? Or is rather the absence
of globalization and foreign investment to blame for the continued misery
in countries, say, like Myanmar, while outward-looking policies dramatically
increased the lot of wide strata of the population in countries like China,
Thailand and India over the last decades?
Theories Explaining Backwardness and Disarticulation
After the "ultimate triumph" of the market economy on a global
scale (Fukuyama) as the result of the collapse of Communism in Eastern
Europe, an intensive debate about the development prospects of Europe's
Southern and Southeastern neighbors set in.
On a global economy level, neo-liberal authors like Barro; Barro and associates;
Crafts; Dadush and Brahmbatt; Dollar and Kraay and Weede generally tend
to think that with the establishment of "economic freedom" positive
patterns of development will prevail in practically all countries.
Cultural theories of development tend to stress that at present development
perspectives for the large region between Morocco in the West and Iran
in the East are not good. Their principal spokesperson today is Huntington,
but also such diverse sources as the UNDP's Arab Human Development Report
(2002) or the World Bank's MENA Report (2002) tend to highlight the various
development constraints in that region. While the UNDP stresses the lack
of democracy, human resource development and gender equality as the main
development blocks, the World Bank highlights the negative heritage of
"Arab Socialism" or past state sector influence.
Dependency authors by contrast explain backwardness and stagnation by
the ever-growing dependent insertion of these countries into the world
economy. Starting with the writings of Perroux, Prebisch and Rothschild
in the 1930s, their leading spokespersons, like Addo; Baran; Bello; Cardoso;
Cordova; Cordova and Silva - Michelena; Dubiel; Feder; Flechsig; Frank;
Frank and associates; Froebel et al.; Gonzales Casanova; Griffin; Griffin
and associates; Kent; Linnemann and Sarma; Müller et al.; Raffer;
Senghaas; Singer; So; Sunkel; and Woehlcke all would stress the unequal
and socially imbalanced nature of development in regions that are highly
dependent on investment from the highly developed countries. Short-term
spurts of growth notwithstanding, long-term growth will be imbalanced
and unequal, and will tend towards high negative current account balances.
Many of these authors focused their attention on Latin America; their
leading spokesperson in the Islamic world is the Egyptian economist Samir
Amin.
Later world system analyses - that started with the writings of the Austro-Hungarian
socialist Karl Polanyi after the First World War - tended to confirm and
expand this dependency argument. Capitalism in the periphery, like in
the center, is characterized by strong cyclical fluctuations, and there
are centers, semi-peripheries and peripheries. The rise of one group of
semi-peripheries tends to be at the cost of another group, but the unequal
structure of the world economy based on unequal exchange tends to remain
stable. Authors from the world system approach, like Arrighi; Arrighi
and associates; Beaud; Bornschier; Chase - Dunn; Chase - Dunn and associates;
Frank and associates; Goldfrank; Goldstein; Hopkins; Hopkins and Wallerstein;
Kiljunen; Modelski; Raffer; Ross and Trachte; So; Tausch and associates;
Walker; and Wallerstein tended to discard the "culturalist"
explanations, offered by Huntington, and rather would support the argument
that world economic position, and not culture, determines conflict. Wallerstein
comes clearly up in defense against demonizing the Arab/Islamic world
and thinks that opposing forces against the present world order will increase
(Wallerstein, 1997: http://fbc.binghamton.edu/iwislam.htm)
Dependency and world system theory generally hold that poverty and backwardness
in poor countries - like the Islamic world - are caused by the peripheral
position that these nations have in the international division of labor.
Ever since the capitalist world system evolved, there is a stark distinction
between the nations of the center and the nations of the periphery. Former
Brazilian President Fernando Henrique Cardoso, when he was still a social
scientist, summarized the quantifiable essence of dependency theories
as follows:
* there is a financial and technological penetration by the developed
capitalist centers of the countries of the periphery and semi-periphery
* this produces an unbalanced economic structure both within the peripheral
societies and between them and the centers
* this leads to limitations on self-sustained growth in the periphery
* this favors the appearance of specific patterns of class relations
* these require modifications in the role of the state to guarantee both
the functioning of the economy and the political articulation of a society,
which contains, within itself, foci of inarticulateness and structural
imbalance (Cardoso, 1979)
A rising degree of monopolization in the leading center countries over
time determines that, in order to keep the share of wages at least constant,
a rising exploitation of the raw material producers sets in to offset
the balance. There is a massive, internationally published evidence that
speaks in favor of dependency theory. However, it would be wrong to portray
dependency simply in terms of MNC penetration, and to neglect other aspects
of that relationship. Such authors as Singer and Tausch have put emphasis
on the resource balance as an indicator of the weight of foreign saving.
Other formulations of dependency insisted on 'unequal exchange' which,
according to one such formulation, hampers development (i.e. double factorial
terms of trade of the respective country are < 1.0; see Raffer, 1987,
Amin, 1975, Kohler/Tausch, 2002). Labor in the export sectors of the periphery
is being exploited, while monopolistic structures of international trade
let the centers profit from the high prices of their exports to the world
markets in comparison to their labor productivity.
Neo-dependency and world system schools (see Tausch and Prager, 1993)
would fear in addition that the most recent tendencies of world capitalism
will strongly work against high female employment and create female unemployment,
and they would especially expect two hypotheses to hold
(i) transnational capital marginalizes female labor power
(ii) the dynamics of growth turn away from those countries, where women
still have a strong position on the labor market.
The measurement scale, compatible with such hypotheses, would be the
share of women in total employment and its trade-off with growth rates.
The gender empowerment indicator series, first developed by the UNDP for
the UNO-Women-Conference in Beijing 1995, provides a further testing ground
for the different feminist social theories of world development.
However, neo-liberal thought would caution against such conclusions. Feminism
per se might positively affect development patterns, but it might also
work like a 'distribution coalition' that tries to influence - like all
distribution coalitions - the results of the market via political pressure.
Instead of changing the sexist distribution of human capital endowments,
and thus changing the "starting capital" of women in society,
feminism, the argument would say, tries to directly influence distributive
relations via politics alone. The result could be - like with any distribution
coalition - long-run stagnation and worsening income and other inequality.
Our theory has to be qualified in one important further respective. Militarism
will under certain circumstances be a 'substitute' for a Keynesian strategy
and might have positive consequences for employment, and hence, perhaps
also distribution issues. Apart from that, it is not entirely clear whether
- like it or not - a negative short term or middle term relation between
militarism and economic growth is to be ruled out entirely. Earlier research
by Tausch (1993 - 2002) replicated some of the surprising findings by
Weede in this respect.
Other schools of thought (Holzmann et al.; European Roundtable of Industrialists)
have stressed recently the importance of pension reforms in a globally
aging society as a determinant of growth and development. Aging societies
and inadequate pension systems, and not culture, economic freedom or dependency
alone, are to blame for the negative development perspectives in many
countries. Without adequate pension reform, aging will be an increasing
burden on the comparative growth and development perspectives of the aging
richer nations.
Ever since the writings of Colemann (1965), also education should be mentioned
among the determining variables of the development performance of a country.
Education and human capital formation figure prominently in the "Human
Development Reports" of the United Nations Development Programme
as variables which determine positively the development outcome. For the
UNDP it has been self-evident over the last decade that gender empowerment
and the re-direction of public expenditures away from defense will positively
contribute to a positive development outcome.
However, neo-liberal thought would caution against such premature conclusions.
Public education expenditures are still public expenditures, and it is
entirely conceivable that in the long run public education expenditures
might negatively affect the development chances of a society, not because
they are education expenditures, but because they are still public expenditures.
For such a theoretical understanding, University reform and University
privatization would be important political steps to achieve a more viable
development.
Developing the Research Design
The almost unlimited number of empirical studies on peripheral capitalism
and development on a world level in the B-phase of the Kondratieff cycle
from 1965 onwards go back, in a way, to the classic essay published by
Johan Galtung in the Journal of Peace Research (Galtung, 1971). For Galtung,
income inequality, and hence, relative poverty in the nations of the world
system is linked to trade partner concentration of the peripheral country
and a trade structure that relies on the exports of raw materials and
the imports of finished products. Bornschier, Chase-Dunn, and their school
later on reformulated the argument: not only income inequality, but also
long term economic growth are being negatively determined by dependency
from transnational capital, to be measured by a weighted share of transnational
investment penetration per the economic and demographic size of a nation.
Later essays extended the argument to other indicators of human well-being,
the environment as well as democratic stability. Macroquantitative analyses
modeled around the dependency/world system school generally have confirmed
dependency arguments. According to these quantitative data analyses, there
are powerful influences at work, which cause inequality and external imbalances
in the periphery.(1).
There has been a tendency in more recent cross-national research to focus
not only on such variables as economic growth, income inequality and a
few other indicators of social well-being, but to interpret "well-being"
more widely to include also democracy, the environment, gender inequality
and human development. Research results by Alderson and Nielsen; Beer;
Bullock and Firebaugh; Burns et al.; DeSoysa and Oneal; Dixon, Fain et
al.; Firebaugh and Beck.; Firebaugh; Hertz et al.; Kick et al.; Korzeniewicz
and Moran; London and Williams; Meyer; Shen and Williamson; Shin, Smith;
Tausch; Ward; Wimberley; and Wimberley and Bello in general terms indicate
that there is reason to believe that the march of global capitalism not
only negatively affects the distribution of economic values in the world
system, but also of democracy, human development, gender equality and
the quality of the environment.
The present essay is well placed within that tradition, but qualifies
these results in important respects. What are the negative social and
ecological consequences of the dependent insertion into the world economy
on a global scale and in the Southern and Southeastern neighborhood of
Europe? Countries as far apart as large parts of Africa and Asia, just
as Poland from 1795 - 1918, did not constitute a national state during
the important era of the Industrial Revolution. Their economies were geared
to the needs of others, i.e. their colonizers. The structural heterogeneity
between the different economic sectors on the one hand and the 'modern',
export oriented sector, the medium sector and the 'traditional sector'
in agriculture, industry and services, became the main reason for the
unequal income distribution in the countries of the periphery. Colonial
trade, foreign investment in the 19th Century, import substitution in
the first half of the 20th Century, and the new international division
of labor that we observe from the middle of the 1960s onwards did not
really change the structures of inequality in the world system. While
mass demand and agricultural structures (Elsenhans, 1983) were responsible
for the transition from the tributary mode of production in Western Europe
to capitalism from the Long 16th Century onwards, periphery capitalism
was and is characterized by the following main tendencies (Amin, 1973
- 1997):
1. regression in both agriculture and small scale industry characterizes
the period after the onslaught of foreign domination and colonialism
2. unequal international specialization of the periphery leads to the
concentration of activities in export oriented agriculture and or mining.
Some industrialization of the periphery is possible under the condition
of low wages, which, together with rising productivity, determine that
unequal exchange sets in (double factorial terms of trade < 1.0; see
Raffer, 1987 )
3. these structures determine in the long run a rapidly growing tertiary
sector with hidden unemployment and the rising importance of rent in the
overall social and economic system
4. the development blocks of peripheral capitalism (chronic current account
balance deficits, re-exported profits of foreign investments, deficient
business cycles of the periphery that provide important markets for the
centers during world economic upswings)
5. structural imbalances in the political and social relationships, inter
alia a strong 'compradore' element and the rising importance of state
capitalism and an indebted state class
For this reason, our concept of dependence at least includes three dimensions:
* unequal exchange
* MNC penetration
* the resource balance.
The analysis of development patterns in the 1990s and beyond is complicated
by the fact that capitalism develops not smoothly, but with very strong
and self-repeating ups and downs, called cycles. Our analysis starts from
well-known empirical research results of Joshua Goldstein, Volker Bornschier,
and Luigi Scandella on this issue (Tausch, 1997, 1998). Cyclical fluctuations
have also a profound effect on cross-national comparisons of economic
growth and societal development in the medium and long run. What could
have been spectacular long-run growth, in the end might turn out to be
just a short run cyclical spurt after a long recession. For that reason,
we include "development stability" among the dependent variables
of our analysis.
Cycle time plays, as we already stated, an important role in our approach.
Arrighi's thought is especially worthwhile mentioning here: that the logic
of accumulation on a world scale shifts along time, and that we again
witness during the 1980s and beyond a deregulated phase of world capitalism
with a logic, characterized - in contrast to earlier regulatory cycles
- by the dominance of financial capital. Arrighi further teaches us that
even a century can be a 'short run' in the evolution of world capitalism.
For Arrighi, there are signal crises of world capitalism (the usual Kondratieff
depressions), and there are terminal crises of the world system, like
the great crash of the early 1340s, which marked the beginning of the
Genoese age, the 1560s, which marked the beginning of the Dutch era, the
1750s and 1760s, which marked the beginning of the British era, and the
1930s, which were the terminal crisis of British world capitalist dominance.
Regulation can be successful, like after 1560, and 1930, and deregulation
can be successful, like after 1340, 1760, and - most probably - the 1980s
(compiled from Arrighi, 1995).
Tausch, 1998; and Tausch and Herrmann, 2002 reached the conclusion that
stocks of achieved globalization - measured by the UNCTAD indicator transnational
investment stocks per total GDP in 1985 - significantly and negatively
affected 15 of the reported 19 development dimensions in 123 countries
with fairly complete data during the period from 1965 to around 1993 -
with the development dimensions ranging from economic growth to human
development, gender empowerment, life expectancy, human and civil rights
performance, economic equality etc.
A later and partial replication of these results came to the conclusion
that in 134 countries under investigation with fairly complete data from
1960 to 1995 - including the world of former Communism - both the UNCTAD
variable - stocks of MNC capital per total GDP - as well as a new indicator
of unequal exchange (simply based on the reciprocal value of the exchange
rate deviation index, i.e. 1/ERDI) negatively and significantly affected
several development processes.
Questions of Measurement of the Multivariate Analysis
The choice of the 109 countries was determined by the availability of
a complete data series for the independent variables (if not mentioned
otherwise, UNDP data):
* % population, aged >65y, 1998
* % women in government, ministerial level
* (I-S)/GDP (calculated from UNDP; investments minus savings per GDP)
* economic freedom (Heritage Foundation and Wall Street Journal website
for economic freedom, 2000)
* EU-membership
* Islamic conference membership (OIC website)
* ln (GDP PPP pc)^2 (natural log GDP per capita in real purchasing power
parities)
* ln(GDP PPP pc) (natural log GDP per capita in real purchasing power
parities)
* military expenditure as % of GDP
* MNC PEN 1995 (UNCTAD)
* public education expenditure per GDP
* unequal exchange (calculated from UNDP, concept: 1/ERDI; exchange rate
deviation index)
The following dependent variables were used; with pair wise deletion
of missing values each time determining the number of countries entering
into the 14 final regression equations:
* % people not expected to survive age 60
* CO2 emissions per capita
* development stability (year with highest real income minus year with
lowest real income) since 1975 (calculated from UNDP)
* ESI-Index (Yale/Columbia environment sustainability index project website)
* Factor Social Development (Tausch, 2001b, calculated from 35 UNDP social
indicators, SPSS factor analysis)
* female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity rate
* female share in total life years (calculated from UNDP - share of female
life expectancy in the sum of male and female life expectancy)
* GDP output per kg energy use ("eco-social market economy")
* GDP per capita annual growth rate, 1990-98
* human development index
* life expectancy, 1995-2000
* Political rights violations (Freedom House, 200016)
* share of income/consumption richest 20% to poorest 20%
* unemployment (UN social indicators website)
The following countries featured in the analysis: Albania; Algeria; Argentina;
Armenia; Australia; Austria; Azerbaijan; Bahrain; Bangladesh; Belarus;
Belgium; Belize; Bolivia; Botswana; Brazil; Bulgaria; Burkina Faso; Burundi;
Cambodia; Chad; Chile; China; Colombia; Costa Rica; Côte d'Ivoire;
Croatia; Cyprus; Czech Republic; Denmark; Egypt; El Salvador; Estonia;
Ethiopia; Fiji; Finland; France; Gabon; Gambia; Georgia; Germany; Ghana;
Greece; Guatemala; Guyana; Honduras; Hungary; India; Indonesia; Iran,
Islamic Rep. of; Ireland; Israel; Italy; Japan; Jordan; Kazakhstan; Kenya;
Kyrgyzstan; Lao People's Dem. Rep.; Latvia; Lebanon; Lesotho; Lithuania;
Luxembourg; Madagascar; Malawi; Malaysia; Mali; Malta; Mauritania; Mexico;
Moldova, Rep. of; Mongolia; Namibia; Nepal; Netherlands; New Zealand;
Nicaragua; Nigeria; Norway; Pakistan; Panama; Philippines; Poland; Portugal;
Romania; Russian Federation; Saudi Arabia; Senegal; Singapore; Slovakia;
Slovenia; South Africa; Spain; Sri Lanka; Sweden; Switzerland; Syrian
Arab Republic; Tajikistan; Thailand; Tunisia; Turkey; Uganda; United Kingdom;
United States; Uzbekistan; Venezuela; Yemen; Zambia; Zimbabwe
Our presentation of the variables used in the analysis will be kept to
a minimum. Among the dependent variables, we just mention MNC penetration,
unequal exchange and the resource balance as the three "master variables"
of dependency. Unequal exchange is strongest in the periphery, and weakest
in the centers, with the semi-periphery showing medium levels of exposure
to unequal exchange. Foreign saving, for its turn, is strongest in many
parts of Latin America, Southern Africa, in the "new Europe"
and in China and in several countries of Southeast Asia. In general terms,
we observe today high levels of MNC penetration in the "dominion
economies" like Australia and Canada, in Western Europe, in some
parts of Eastern Europe, in Central Asia, other parts of the former USSR,
in many parts of Latin America, Southern and Western Africa, in Egypt,
in Tunisia, and in China and Southeast Asia.
During the 1990s, penetration by transnational capital dramatically increased
in many parts of Europe (especially in what was described by Donald Rumsfeld,
US Secretary of Defense, recently as "the new Europe"); in eastern
Latin America, in Southern Africa, in Central Asia and in South and Southeast
Asia. However, there was a dramatic decrease of MNC penetration in most
countries of the Arab world during the second half of the 1990s. Among
the dependent variables perhaps only the environmental stability index
might be not so well known in the macro-quantitative research community.
The ESI Index is a measure of the overall progress towards environmental
sustainability and was developed for 142 countries. ESI scores are based
upon 20 core indicators, each of which combines two to eight variables
for a total of 68 underlying variables. It is the first time in the research
literature that a single yardstick of sustainable development has been
developed. The picture for the region of the MENA countries is rather
mixed, with Turkey being classified ahead of the United Kingdom and on
an equal level with Italy. For the multivariate analysis, we will group
our variables into the following dimensions of development:
1 indicator political democracy
* Political rights violations (Freedom House, 2000 )
4 indicators human development
* % people not expected to survive age 60
* Factor Social Development (Tausch, 2001b, calculated from 35 UNDP social
indicators, SPSS factor analysis )
* human development index
* life expectancy, 1995-2000
3 indicators environmental quality
* CO2 emissions per capita
* ESI-Index (Yale/Columbia environment sustainability index project website)
* GDP output per kg energy use
1 indicator development stability
* development stability (year with highest real income minus year with
lowest real income) since 1975 (calculated from UNDP)
1 indicator growth
* GNP per capita annual growth rate, 1990-98
2 indicators social inclusion
* share of income/consumption richest 20% to poorest 20%
* unemployment (UN social indicators website)
2 indicators gender justice
* female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity rate
* female share in total life years (calculated from UNDP - share of female
life expectancy in the sum of male and female life expectancy)
These variables are explained by the following predictors:
3 indicators of dependency
* (I-S)/GDP (calculated from UNDP) (resource balance)
* MNC PEN 1995 (UNCTAD)
* unequal exchange (calculated from UNDP, concept: 1/ERDI)
1 variable adherence to the advice by international financial institutions
* Economic freedom (Heritage Foundation and Wall Street Journal website
for economic freedom, 2000)
2 variables world political or world cultural identities
* EU-membership
* Islamic conference membership (OIC website)
1 variable aging society
* % population, aged >65y, 1998
1 variable political feminism
* % women in government, ministerial level
1 variable militarism
* military expenditure as % of GDP
1 variable public education effort
* public education expenditure per GDP
2 control variables for development level, interacting
* ln(GDP PPP pc)
* ln (GDP PPP pc)^2
We have to start here from the assumption that the basic tools of multivariate
macro-quantitative analysis in political science and sociology are known
to the audience of this article (for further literature on the subject,
see Achen; Clauss and Ebner; Huang; Jackman; Kriz; Krzysztofiak. and Luszniewicz;
Lewis - Beck; Microsoft Excel; Opp and Schmidt).
A sophisticated re-analysis of the tendencies of world development in
the 1990s should start from the assumption that the development level
has a decisive, non-linear trade-off with subsequent development performance:
poor countries increase rapidly their average life expectancy or economic
growth and they quickly reduce their income inequality etc.
Social scientists interpreted this effect mainly in view of an acceleration
of economic growth in middle-income countries vis-à-vis the poor
countries and in view of the still widening gap between the poorest periphery
nations ('have-nots') and the 'haves' among the former Second and Third
World (Tausch/Herrmann, 2002):
(Equation 1) development performance = a1 + b1* ln (PCItn) - b2* (ln (PCItn))2
The same function is also applied to income inequality and the rest of
our 14 indicators, following a famous essay published by S. Kuznets in
1955. Growth and development accelerate with redistribution, and then
stagnate. In general terms, we explain development performance by the
following standard multiple cross-national development research equation:
(Equation 2) development performance 1990 - end 1990s = a1 +- b1*first
part curvilinear function of development level +- b2*second part curvilinear
function of development level +- b3...*transnational investment per GDP
(UNCTAD) mid 1990s +- b4...*unequal exchange (1/ERDI) +- b5...* foreign
saving +- b6...* military expenditures per GDP +- b7...* aging +- b8...*
public education expenditures per GDP +-b9 * membership in the Islamic
Conference +- b10 * European Union membership +- b11 * economic freedom
In the following, we will present our results about the effects of globalization
in a multi-variate perspective.
The Final Results for 109 Countries
In general terms, several but not all aspects of the presented theories
are confirmed, while other central assumptions of both the "Washington
Consensus" and of its dependency theory counterpart are rejected.
Also, theories about aging; feminist theories; human resource theories;
military Keynesian theories/peace theories (i.e. theories maintaining
that militarism has a very bad effect on long-run development); globalization
critique and international economic integration theories have to tally
with both positive and negative effects of their key indicators on different
measurements of social, environmental and economic welfare, indicating
that the time of the "quick fixes" has definitely gone and that
contemporary development realities are very complex indeed. It should
be noted that in this and in the following presentations, we already considered
duly that "good effects" are "good effects" and that
"bad effects" are "bad effects" when presenting our
results; i.e. a development strategy that increases, say, under 60 mortality
rates, is a bad strategy and thus has negative effects.
Aging is part and parcel of the structure of industrialized societies,
East and West. Aging contributes to a generalized scarcity of labor, which
in turn leads to improved distributive relationships between the rich
and the poor. However, several negative effects must also be considered
properly - especially the negative effects of an aging population structure
on the process of human development, which is basically the dire consequence
of unreformed pension systems (Tausch, 2003).
aging % population, aged >65y, 1998
· GDP output per kg energy use (eco-social market economy) - positive
effect
· female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity
rate - positive effect
· share of income/consumption richest 20% to poorest 20% (income
redistribution) - positive effect
· unemployment (UN) (employment) - positive effect
· CO2 emissions per capita (Kyoto) - negative effect
· female share in total life years - negative effect
· % people not expected to survive age 60 (survival) - negative
effect
· life expectancy, 1995-2000 - negative effect
· Factor Social Development - negative effect
· human development index - negative effect
Political feminism has an aggregate positive effect on many phenomena
of human and ecological development, but it fails to transform political
power into improved employment and distribution structures. This is due
mainly to the process of distribution coalition formation, featuring so
prominently in neo-liberal theories of economic growth (see especially,
the writings of Weede).
political feminism % women in government, ministerial level
· CO2 emissions per capita (Kyoto) - positive effect
· female share in total life years - positive effect
· % people not expected to survive age 60 (survival) - positive
effect
· life expectancy, 1995-2000 - positive effect
· Factor Social Development - positive effect
· human development index - positive effect
· GDP output per kg energy use (eco-social market economy) - negative
effect
· female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity
rate - negative effect
· share of income/consumption richest 20% to poorest 20% (income
redistribution) - negative effect
· unemployment (UN) (employment) - negative effect
As one of the three main indicators of dependency, the reliance on foreign
savings eases the distribution burden against the poorer segments of society
during the accumulation process, but it has several negative effects on
a variety of other development processes, including the environment and
political democracy.
foreign saving (I-S)/GDP
· share of income/consumption richest 20% to poorest 20% (income
redistribution) - positive effect
· CO2 emissions per capita (Kyoto) - negative effect
· human development index - negative effect
· ESI-Index (sustainability) - negative effect
· Political rights - negative effect
Economic freedom increases the rationality of the societal resource allocation
and leads towards an improved development stability but it fails to resolve
two basic issues: overall environmental stress and societal sexism in
the employment sphere. Unfettered liberalization hurts women as the more
vulnerable group in society.
economic freedom
· CO2 emissions per capita (Kyoto) - positive effect
· GDP output per kg energy use (eco-social market economy) - positive
effect
· development stability (year with highest real income minus year
with lowest real income) since 1975 - positive effect
· ESI-Index (sustainability) - negative effect
· female share in total life years - negative effect
· female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity
rate - negative effect
Military expenditures have a certain Keynesian effect but they contribute
towards a worse environmental balance. Military expenditures lead towards
a drying up of what Marxists term "the reserve army of labor",
which, in turn, leads to a certain better social cohesion and employment
gender balance. But militarized structures consume large amounts of fossil
fuel, with advanced air forces especially contributing to that process.
· female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity
rate - positive effect
· share of income/consumption richest 20% to poorest 20% (income
redistribution) - positive effect
· CO2 emissions per capita (Kyoto) - negative effect
· GDP output per kg energy use (eco-social market economy) - negative
effect
MNC penetration contributes to an improved ESI Index and towards better
female employment, but it has negative consequences for human survival
and life expectancy. In addition, an interesting phenomenon worthy of
further research is the interconnection between decaying public services,
decaying public transport and decaying public health services in the host
countries of transnational investment on the one hand and the strategic
policies of transnational corporations on the other hand, concentrated
on the private sector, private transport, private medical services and
the private automobile. The strengthening triple alliance between the
MNCs, local capital and the state is a net result of the globalization
process, and it still has dire social consequences as well.
dependency on foreign capital MNC PEN 1995
· female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity
rate - positive effect
· ESI-Index (sustainability) - positive effect
· % people not expected to survive age 60 (survival) - negative
effect
· life expectancy, 1995-2000 - negative effect
Human resources and human development investments ever since the publication
of the first United Nations Human Development Reports in the early 1990s
are regarded as the key towards a socially equitable and sustainable development.
However, as often happens in development theory, the early optimism regarding
the effects of one variable has soon to be qualified.
There are very surprising clear-cut negative interactions between public
education expenditure and an eco-social market economy and political democracy.
Positive effects exist as well, but they are not statistically significant.
A plausible intervening variable, which we did not as yet consider in
our investigation, could be the years of experience of a country as a
centrally planned economy.
public education expenditure per GDP
· GDP output per kg energy use (eco-social market economy) - negative
effect
· Political rights - negative effect
Unequal exchange has the most clear-cut negative results of all dependency
indicators on the process of development, as understood in this investigation;
especially on democracy, the environment, gender justice and employment.
The positive effect on income redistribution has to be seen in the context
of the siphoning-off of the surplus value from periphery countries that
reduces the share of the richest 20 % in total income distribution.
unequal exchange
· share of income/consumption richest 20% to poorest 20% (income
redistribution) - positive effect
· GDP output per kg energy use (eco-social market economy) - negative
effect
· Political rights - negative effect
· female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity
rate - negative effect
· ESI-Index (sustainability) - negative effect
· CO2 emissions per capita (Kyoto) - negative effect
· female share in total life years - negative effect
· unemployment (UN) (employment) - negative effect
There are very diverse views nowadays on the European Union. As a recent
paper, published in the journal "Parameters" of the US Army
maintains (Wilkie, 2003): "Still, there are those on both sides of
the Atlantic who believe that the European Union, as an old-fashioned
socialist bureaucracy, is "fundamentally unreformable" and also
culturally hostile to the United States" (Wilkie, 2003: 46)
There is a wide range of literature now available that highlights the
negative effects of European integration in a globalized world economy
(for a survey of the literature and politometric evidence, see Tausch
and Herrmann, 2001). In the present research design, the most considerable
effect is the negative trade-off between EU membership and political democracy,
once you control for the other intervening variables that together explain
jointly 66.1 % of political rights violations.
EU-membership
· Political rights - negative effect
Our results about the European Union might be considered more provocative
still, when we also consider that - contrary to popular assumptions -
membership in the Islamic Conference is not an impediment against political
democracy. Our results clearly contradict many of the expectations inherent
in the writings of Professor Samuel Huntington. 4 development indicators
- 2 for the environment, 1 on human development, and 1 on democracy -
are positively and significantly determined by membership in the Islamic
Conference, once you properly control for the effects of the other influencing
variables. However, gender justice and redistribution remain the "Achilles
heel" of today's members in the Islamic Conference, strengthening
the cause of those who advocate - like in the United Nations Arab Human
Development Report - more social inclusion and more gender justice in
the region.
Islamic conference membership
· Political rights - positive effect
· GDP output per kg energy use (eco-social market economy) - positive
effect
· CO2 emissions per capita (Kyoto) - positive effect
· life expectancy, 1995-2000 - positive effect
· share of income/consumption richest 20% to poorest 20% (income
redistribution) - negative effect
· female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity
rate - negative effect
The well-known acceleration and maturity effects of development have to
be qualified in an important way. Ever since the days of Simon Kuznets,
development researchers have applied curve-linear formulations in order
to capture these effects. However, the results for equation 1 above are
not as clear-cut as one might have expected; and - in addition - the direction
of the influence does hardly correspond with the equation. The curve-linear
function of growth, being regressed on the natural logarithm of development
level and its square, is sometimes called the 'Matthew's effect' following
Matthew's (13, 12): "For whosoever hath, to him shall be given, and
he shall have more abundance: but whosoever hath not, for him shall be
taken away even that he hath."
Social scientists interpreted this effect mainly in view of an acceleration
of economic growth in middle-income countries vis-à-vis the poor
countries and in view of the still widening gap between the poorest periphery
nations ('have-nots') and the 'haves' among the semi-periphery countries
(Jackman, 1982). Their hypothesis is only partially confirmed here - there
is no significant acceleration at low levels of development, but a significant
econonmic growth stagnation/saturation effect. The first expression -
+ b1* ln (PCItn) - yields the following results:
acceleration effects development ln(GDP PPP pc)
· female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity
rate - positive effect
The second part of the "Kuznets-curve" - b2* (ln (PCItn))2 -
has today the following results:
maturity effects development ln (GDP PPP pc)^2
· female economic activity rate as % of male economic activity
rate - positive effect
· life expectancy, 1995-2000 - positive effect
· share of income/consumption richest 20% to poorest 20% (income
redistribution) - positive effect
· ESI-Index (sustainability) - positive effect
· female share in total life years - positive effect
· human development index - positive effect
· Factor Social Development - positive effect
· GNP per capita annual growth rate, 1990-98 - negative effect
Implications for Policy
By far the most negative influence on development is wielded by unequal
exchange, followed by the aging process (especially without pension reform)
and certain negative aspects of feminist distribution coalitions in society.
By far the most positive effects on social, ecological and economic development
come about by the maturity effects of development, followed by the positive
aspects of feminism, the aging process and membership in the Islamic Conference.
With all the talk about dependency, globalization or the "Washington
Consensus" notwithstanding, it is shown that feminism, pension reform,
and the maturity effects of capitalism open up new horizons of future
development debates. The variables
* political feminism % women in government, ministerial level
* aging % population, aged >65y, 1998
* maturity effects development ln (GDP PPP pc)^2
* unequal exchange
are far more relevant in explaining our 14 development dimensions than
the traditional "stars" of the debate, the political and left
and right, pro- and anti-globalization movements, culturalist development
theories etc. notwithstanding. The variables
* Islamic conference membership
* economic freedom
* foreign saving (I-S)/GDP
* military expenditure as % of GDP
* dependency on foreign capital MNC PEN 1995
* public education expenditure per GDP
* acceleration effects development ln(GDP PPP pc)
* EU-membership
on the other hand do not have so many significant effects (insignificant
effects > 50 %) as the "new" variables (insignificant effects
< 50 %), which were analyzed in this article and which will determine
future development outcomes in a decisive way.
Let us turn to the issue of Islamic development efficiency. The empirical
record, presented in this essay, speaks a clear language in favor of Islamic
democracy and against those in the West that attempt to treat Islamic
cultural heritage as a general development burden. A careful reading of
what theologians - most notably, also leading Christian experts on Islam
among them - positively have to say on Islamic humanism and its interesting
institutions of zakat and sadaqat is in stark contrast to the contemporary
rhetoric of cultural warfare; basic Islamic institutions have enormously
many aspects to offer to world development. A glance at the literature
could easily convince anyone about the richness of Islamic social doctrine
and Islamic social philosophy (Abdullah and Khoury, 1984; Armstrong, 2001;
Khoury, 1980, 1981, 1991; Kunzmann and associates, 1996; Russell, 1999;
Tibi, 1985, 1992, 2001). Zakat is the first institution of social security
in the world system. Payment of 2 1/2 percent of savings of the zakat
fund is one of the fundamental duties of a Muslim. The State is responsible
to collect zakat and makes arrangements for its distribution; while sadaqat
is paid at no fixed rate (see also: The Light of Islam website at http://home.swipnet.se/islam/articles/Non-Muslim.htm).
Our evidence shows that the majority of Islamic countries transformed
their "growth" much better to the benefit of "life quality"
(average life expectancy) than most other societies around the globe.
At the same time, the UNDP data set shows that life expectancy as the
most direct indicator of life quality in the world system has dramatically
increased in the regions of the Middle East and in the Andean countries
of Latin America, while in Southern Africa and in Eastern Europe there
was a stagnation over the long period 1970 - 2000.
Seen in such a way, the contrary of common beliefs is true: "Kemalism",
"Arab socialism" and other "isms" were quite successful,
while the "Washington Consensus" strategies put in place after
1989 in Eastern Europe and the former USSR proved to be one of the utmost
development failures in human history.
At a time, when leading protagonists of the "Consensus" proclaim
that growth is simply good for the poor, it is time to reckon by quantitative
means the complicated relationships between growth and the social and
ecological dimensions of growth.
Protagonists of the thesis that growth is good for the poor would have
to expect a 1:1 correlation between these two variables. But this is clearly
not the case.
High growth and high life expectancy increases are certainly good for
the poor; but equally interesting are the cases of those countries that
had negative economic growth (<0.0 % per annum) and yet experienced
a life expectancy increase of more than 9 years all over the period of
the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s. These countries were Libya, Saudi-Arabia,
Bolivia, Algeria, Iran, Nicaragua, Peru, United Arab Emirates, El Salvador,
Senegal, and Comoros. So, if growth is good for the poor, is stagnation
also good for the poor?
There were indeed high-growth countries (real growth per capita > 3.0
% per annum) with dramatic life expectancy increases of 9 years or more
- countries that correspond to a revised "growth is good for the
poor" theory. These countries were Bhutan, Viet Nam, Indonesia, Maldives,
Laos, India, South Korea, Chile, Cape Verde, Thailand, Equatorial Guinea,
and Malaysia. However, the problem for the Dollar and Kray school of thought
("growth is good for the poor - > globalization is good for growth,
ergo: globalization is good for the poor") is here that these countries
were not precisely "shining examples" of world economic openness.
In reality many of them combined "openness" with various degrees
of import substitution and government control. Their long-run growth was
really good for the poor. But what about the neo-liberal high-growth country
Botswana (> 3.0 % per annum) that had a life expectancy reversal of
8.7 years since the 1970s, brought about by the AIDS epidemic and rampant
poverty?
It also emerges that the Islamic countries are among the best performers
on our scale measuring exceptional human development increases in the
world system (already taking into account past levels of human development).
Development is a contradictory and dialectical process. There is no single
strategy, that has only positive results, and there is no strategy, that
has only negative results. No single development theory today captures
all these negative and positive effects that interact together. At this
stage, perhaps, the question will arise - what are the real policy implications,
then, of this kind of analysis? It should be clear that a reliance on
the "Washington Consensus" alone will not "fix" the
performance of countries beyond a better and more predictable "development
stability". The most consistent consequence of the "dependency"
analysis of this essay is the realization that a reliance on foreign capital
in the short term might bring about positive consequences for employment
- especially female employment - but that the long-term negative consequences
of dependence in the social sphere, but also for sustainable development,
outweigh the immediate, positive effects. Our three-fold empirical understanding
of the process of globalization - reliance on foreign savings, MNC penetration
and unequal exchange, - goes beyond the average analysis of the workings
of dependency structures and shows how different aspects of dependency
negatively affect development performance. The integration of the countries
of the periphery into larger currency blocs - quite contrary to what the
"Washington Consensus" has to say about "competitive currencies"
- will be one of the most important tasks for international development
strategies for years to come. Left for themselves in the capitalist world
economy, the countries of the periphery and semi-periphery will always
be victims of international currency instabilities. In the light of earlier
published analyses, it is no surprise that "unequal exchange"
(1/ERDI; ERDI being the exchange rate deviation index) is again established
to be the most important dependency variable today, far more important
in its negative effects on social and sustainable development than the
UNCTAD data series on MNC penetration. European Union integration, this
analysis again shows, on the other hand is not a quick fix for many of
the social ills of the periphery and semi-periphery. The EU under present
conditions fails to have sufficiently enough dynamic effects and its democratic
deficits become ever more clear. In terms of the size of the quantitative
effects on the 14 dimensions of development under investigation here,
it is shown that the new political structures associated with political
feminism that substituted patriarchic structures inherent in practically
all world regions for much of the 19th and the early 20th Century have
a very considerable effect on the development outcomes of today. As we
have outlined above, feminism in power - i.e. the share of women in positions
of political decision making - achieves to transform many aspects of development,
but, as other "distribution coalitions" before it, creates certain
aspects of stagnation as well and thus is not free from the effects of
the logic of "collective action" that is at the heart of the
neo-liberal doctrine of today (see especially the works Olson and Weede).
In the 21st Century, the process of aging and the necessity of pension
reform, closely linked to that process, also cannot be overlooked anymore.
In our analysis, unequal exchange, aging, and political feminism achieve
the majority of the significant effects on the 14 development dimensions
under investigation here, i.e. far more than the "master" variables
of earlier debates, like "economic freedom" versus "MNC
penetration". As has been argued elsewhere, globalization critics
especially must start to look at pensions and pension funds seriously
- because the way, in which you manage the savings of society for old
age, you also manage technological innovation and world systems position
in general (Tausch, 2003). It is also evident from the analysis presented
in this article that Islamic culture is not a development blockade; on
the contrary. Membership in the Islamic Conference has - ceteris paribus
- a very positive effect on political democracy, on life expectancy, and
on our indicators of the Kyoto-process and the eco-social market economy.
Far from being a "religion of the Middle Ages" Islam has an
important message for the 21st Century. It is to be hoped that socially
progressive forces in the MENA countries will achieve a better monetary
distribution of incomes and a better gender distribution of work in the
societies concerned in the future.
This article shows some of the limitations of the contemporary optimism
regarding the overall early and only positive effects of EU-accession.
According to one of the leading authorities on the European Union in Turkey,
Professor Sübidey Togan from Bilkent University in Ankara, we can
expect the following to happen:
Integration will be beneficial for Turkey as it will remove the distortions
in the price system, boosting the allocative efficiency in the economy,
which in turn will make the country a better place to invest. Furthermore,
with accession Turkey will be eligible for EU structural funds. The increase
in infrastructural investments will contribute to economic growth in Turkey.
In addition, Turkey will reap benefits from monetary integration, and
finally, Turkey will benefit from migration of Turkish labor to the EU.
However, the welfare gains that will be derived by Turkey from integration
will have a price. The price will be the adjustment costs associated with
the attainment of macroeconomic stability, adoption of CAP, liberalization
of services and network industries, and complying with EU environmental
directives.
According to Eurobarometer (2001) 59 percent of the Turkish population
supports EU membership and 68 percent of the population declares that
it would support the country's membership to the EU if a referendum were
to be held on this issue. This high percentage of support for EU membership
could partially be explained by the economic benefits that Turkey expects
to derive from membership. Equally important is the recognition in Turkey
that the system of governance of a rule-based society, as in the EU with
its institutions, may provide a better system for meeting the demands
of various groups in the society. Furthermore, the support for EU membership
stems also from the process of Westernization and geo-strategic considerations.
The Turkish accession will also affect the welfare of current members
of the EU. With Turkish accession current members will derive welfare
gains from standard comparative advantage sources and also from growth
effects of integration. Furthermore, migration of Turkish labor to the
EU will affect the welfare level in member countries. The empirical research
on the economic effects of immigration indicates fairly small and on the
whole positive effects; employment opportunities are not affected much,
the wage of low skilled labor is depressed somewhat but that of skilled
labor is raised, and the net present value of public transfers is positive.
In addition to these effects, the EU will have to incur the net annual
budgetary cost of Turkish membership to the EU. Estimates indicate that
this cost will be quite high unless the rules on CAP and structural funds
are changed over the next few years. There will also be political gains
for the EU. Turkey is a large and fast expanding market (Togan, 2002).
But it is shown in this article, that transnational integration is and
remains to be a contradictory process that does not lead 1:1 to a greater
amount of social cohesion and sustainable development in the host countries
of transnational penetration. So, in the words of Osvaldo Sunkel:
'The advancement of modernization introduces, so to speak, a wedge along
the area dividing the integrated from the segregated segments (...) The
effects of the disintegration of each social class has important consequences
for social mobility. (...) Finally, it is very probable that an international
mobility will correspond to the internal mobility, particularly between
the internationalized sectors (...) The process of social disintegration
which has been outlined here probably also affects the social institutions
which provide the bases of the different social groups and through which
they express themselves. Similar tendencies to the ones described for
the global society are, therefore, probably also to be found within the
state, church, armed forces, political parties with a relatively wide
popular base, the universities etc.' (Sunkel, 1972: 18-42).
This picture, drawn more than 3 decades ago, will - in the light of this
empirical analysis - correspond much more to the trajectory of countries
like Turkey over the next decades than optimistic analyses, which are
shared by the majority of decision makers on a European level. The role
of the social scientist then will not be "pathfinders to globalization"
but to become pathfinders for those millions, who will become marginalized
by the process of social disintegration, that goes along and is part and
parcel of transnational integration.
* Arno Tausch is Ministerial Counselor (Ministerialrat) in the Ministry
of Social Security and Generations in Vienna, Austria, and an Associate
Visiting Professor of Political Science at Innsbruck University. He served
as Counselor for Labor and Migration Affairs at the Austrian Embassy in
Warsaw between 1992 and 1999. He published widely on matters of international
development. His latest books include: Global Keynesianism (with Gernot
Kohler) and Globalization and European Integration (with Peter Herrmann),
Hauppauge NY: Nova Science Publishers. The opinions expressed in this
article are strictly his own private academic opinions in the framework
of his venia docendi, and do not necessarily reflect the opinions of the
Austrian Government.
NOTES
1) Flagship essays and book publications of this school were written
among others by Beer and Boswell; Birdsall; Bornschier; Bornschier and
associates; Boswell; Boswell and associates; Bradshaw; Bradshaw and Huang;
Bullock and Firebaugh; Chase - Dunn; Chase - Dunn and associates; Crenshaw;
Delacroix and Ragin; Dixon; Dixon and Boswell; Evans and Timberlake; Fiala;
Firebaugh; Juchler; Kentor; London; London and Robinson; London and Ross;
London and Smith; London and Williams; Moaddel; Muller; Muller and Seligson;
Nollert; Nollert and Fielder; Ragin and Bradshaw; Robinson and London;
Rubinson; Russell; Tausch; Tausch and associates; Timberlake and Kantor;
Timberlake and Williams; Trezzini and Bornschier; and Van Rossem.
REFERENCES
(selection. For full quotations of the literature, see: Tausch/Köhler
and Tausch/Herrmann, 2002 and other recent works by the author of this
article)
Amin S. (1973), 'Le developpement inegal. Essai sur les formations sociales
du capitalisme peripherique' Paris: Editions de Minuit.
Amin S. (1976), 'Unequal Development: An Essay on the Social Formations
of Peripheral Capitalism' New York: Monthly Review Press.
Amin S. (1980) "The Class Structure of the Contemporary Imperialist
System", Monthly Review (USA), 31 (1980), 8: 9-26
Amin S. (1984), 'Was kommt nach der Neuen Internationalen Wirtschaftsordnung?
Die Zukunft der Weltwirtschaft' in 'Rote Markierungen International' (Fischer
H. and Jankowitsch P. (Eds.)), pp. 89 - 110, Vienna: Europaverlag.
Amin S. (1989), 'Eurocentrism' Translated by Russell Moore. New York:
Monthly Review Press.
Amin S. (1992), 'Empire of Chaos' New York: Monthly Review Press.
Amin S. (1994a) 'The Future of Global Polarization', Review (Fernand Braudel
Center, USA), XVII, 3 (Summer), p. 337-347
Amin S. (1994b), 'Die neue kapitalistische Globalisierung - die Herrschaft
des Chaos' Starnberger Forschungsberichte, 3, 4, May: 7 - 26.
Amin S. (1994c), 'Re-reading the postwar period: an intellectual itinerary'
Translated by Michael Wolfers. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Amin S. (1997a) 'Capitalism in the Age of Globalization'. London, England:
Zed Books
Amin S. (1997b), 'Die Zukunft des Weltsystems. Herausforderungen der Globalisierung.
Herausgegeben und aus dem Franzoesischen uebersetzt von Joachim Wilke'
Hamburg: VSA.
Amnesty International (current issues), 'Jahresbericht' Frankfurt a.M.:
Fischer TB.
Bornschier V. (1976), 'Wachstum, Konzentration und Multinationalisierung
von Industrieunternehmen' Frauenfeld and Stuttgart: Huber.
Bornschier V. (1988), 'Westliche Gesellschaft im Wandel' Frankfurt a.M./
New York: Campus.
Bornschier V. (1992), 'The Rise of the European Community. Grasping Towards
Hegemony or Therapy against National Decline in the World Political Economy?'.
Vienna: paper, presented at the First European Conference of Sociology,
August 26 - 29.
Bornschier V. (1996), 'Western society in transition' New Brunswick, N.J.:
Transaction Publishers.
Bornschier V. (1999), 'Hegemonic Transition, West European Unification
and the Future Structure of the Core' in in 'The Future of Global Conflict'
(Bornschier V. and Chase - Dunn Ch. K. (Eds.)), pp. 77 - 98, London, Thousand
Oaks and New Delhi: Sage Publications.
Bornschier V. (Ed.) (1994), 'Conflicts and new departures in world society'
New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Publishers.
Bornschier V. and Chase - Dunn Ch. K (1985), 'Transnational Corporations
and Underdevelopment' N.Y., N.Y.: Praeger.
Bornschier V. and Chase - Dunn Ch. K. (1999), 'Technological Change, Globalization
and Hegemonic Rivalry' in 'The Future of Global Conflict' (Bornschier
V. and Chase - Dunn Ch. K. (Eds.)), pp. 285 - 302, London, Thousand Oaks
and New Delhi: Sage Publications.
Bornschier V. and Heintz P., reworked and enlarged by Th. H. Ballmer -
Cao and J. Scheidegger (1979), 'Compendium of Data for World Systems Analysis'
Machine readable data file, Zurich: Department of Sociology, Zurich University.
Bornschier V. and Nollert M. (1994); 'Political Conflict and Labor Disputes
at the Core: An Encompassing Review for the Post - War Era' in 'Conflicts
and New Departures in World Society' (Bornschier V. and Lengyel P. (Eds.)),
pp. 377 - 403, New Brunswick (U.S.A.) and London: Transaction Publishers,
World Society Studies, Volume 3.
Bornschier V. and Suter Chr. (1992), 'Long Waves in the World System'
in 'Waves, Formations and Values in the World System' (Bornschier V. and
Lengyel P. (Eds.)), pp. 15 - 50, New Brunswick and London: Transaction
Publishers.
Bornschier V. et al. (1980), 'Multinationale Konzerne, Wirtschaftspolitik
und nationale Entwicklung im Weltsystem' Frankfurt a.M.: Campus.
Herrmann P. and Tausch A. (Eds.) Dar al Islam. Europe, the World
System and the ultimate EU-enlargement' Hauppauge, NY: Nova Science Publishers
Muller A., Zulehner P. and Tausch A. (Eds.) Global Capitalism,
Liberation Theology and the Social Sciences' Huntington , N.Y.: Nova Science
Sunkel O. (1966), 'The Structural Background of Development Problems in
Latin America' Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 97, 1: pp. 22 ff.
Sunkel O. (1972/3), 'Transnationale kapitalistische Integration und nationale
Desintegration: der Fall Lateinamerika' in 'Imperialismus und strukturelle
Gewalt. Analysen ueber abhaengige Reproduktion' (Senghaas D. (Ed.)), pp.
258 - 315, Frankfurt a.M.: suhrkamp. English version: 'Transnational capitalism
and national disintegration in Latin America' Social and Economic Studies,
22, 1, March: 132 - 76.
Sunkel O. (1973), 'El subdesarrollo latinoamericano y la teoria del desarrollo'
Mexico: Siglo Veintiuno Editores, 6a edicion.
Sunkel O. (1978a), 'The Development of Development Thinking' in 'Transnational
Capitalism and National Development. New Perspectives on Dependence' (Villamil
J.J. (Ed.)), pp. 19 - 30, Hassocks, Sussex: Harvester Press.
Sunkel O. (1978b), 'Transnationalization and its National Consequences'
in 'Transnational Capitalism and National Development. New Perspectives
on Dependence' (Villamil J.J. (Ed.)), pp. 67 - 94, Hassocks, Sussex: Harvester
Press.
Sunkel O. (1980), 'Transnacionalizacion y dependencia' Madrid: Ediciones
Cultura Hispanica del Instituto de Cooperacion Iberoamericana.
Sunkel O. (1984), 'Capitalismo transnacional y desintegracion nacional
en America Latina' Buenos Aires, Rep. Argentina: Ediciones Nueva Vision.
Sunkel O. (1990), 'Dimension ambiental en la planificacion del desarrollo.
English The environmental dimension in development planning ' 1st ed.
Santiago, Chile: United Nations, Economic Commission for Latin America
and the Caribbean.
Sunkel O. (1991), 'El Desarrollo desde dentro: un enfoque neoestructuralista
para la America Latina' 1. ed. Mexico: Fondo de Cultura Economica.
Sunkel O. (1994), 'Rebuilding capitalism: alternative roads after socialism
and dirigisme' Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press.
Tausch A. (1984, with Mohammed Reza Dehbalaie et al. as coauthors) 'Zentrum,
Peripherie, strukturelle Gewalt und Superruestung. Unterwegs zu einem
politometrischen Modell' Dialog, 1, 1: 72-106
Tausch A. (1986), 'Positions within the Global Order, Patterns of Defense
Policies, and National Development: Austria and Pakistan Compared' in
'Security for the Weak Nations. A Multiple Perspective. A Joint Project
of Pakistani and Austrian Scholars' (S. Farooq Hasnat and Pelinka A. (Eds.)),
pp. 245 - 55, Lahore: Izharsons.
Tausch A. (1987), 'Transnational Corporations and Underdevelopment' Acta
Sociologica, 30, 1: 118 - 121.
Tausch A. (1989a), 'Stable Third World Democracy and the European Model.
A Quantitative Essay' in 'Crisis in Development' (Z. Bablewski and B.
Hettne (Eds.), pp. 131 - 161, Goeteborg: The European Perspectives Project
of the United Nations University, University of Gothenburg, P.A.D.R.I.G.U
- Papers.
Tausch A. (1989b, appeared 1991), 'Armas socialistas, subdesarrollo y
violencia estructural en el Tercer Mundo' Revista Internacional de Sociologia,
CSIC, Madrid, 47, 4: 583 - 716.
Tausch A. (1990) 'Quantitative aspects of a socio-liberal theory of world
development'. Economic Papers, Warsaw School of Economics, Research Institute
for Developing Countries, 23: 64 - 167.
Tausch A. (1991a), 'Russlands Tretmuehle. Kapitalistisches Weltsystem,
lange Zyklen und die neue Instabilitaet im Osten' Eberhard, Munich.
Tausch A. (1991b), 'Jenseits der Weltgesellschaftstheorien. Sozialtransformationen
und der Paradigmenwechsel in der Entwicklungsforschung' Munich: Eberhard.
Tausch A. (1993a), 'Produktivkraft soziale Gerechtigkeit? Europa und die
Lektionen des pazifischen Modells' Munich. Eberhard.
Tausch A. (1993b, with Fred Prager as co-author), 'Towards a Socio - Liberal
Theory of World Development' Basingstoke and New York: Macmillan/St. Martin's
Press.
Tausch A. (1997), 'Schwierige Heimkehr. Sozialpolitik, Migration, Transformation
und die Osterweiterung der Europaeischen Union' Munich: Eberhard.
Tausch A. (1998a) 'Transnational Integration and National Disintegration.'
Electronic publication at the World Systems Archive Working Paper Series
(Coordinator: Christopher K. Chase-Dunn, Johns Hopkins University), http://csf.colorado.edu/wsystems/archive/papers.htm
Tausch A. (1998b) 'Globalization and European Integration' Electronic
book publication at the World Systems Archive (Coordinator: Christopher
K. Chase-Dunn, Johns Hopkins University) http://csf.colorado.edu/wsystems/archive/books/tausch/tauschtoc.htm
Tausch A. (2001a) 'Mature Economy' in 'Routledge Encyclopedia of Political
Economy' London: Routledge.
Tausch A. (2001b) 'Sozial- und gesundheitspolitische Aspekte der EU-Erweiterung'
Band 48, Schriftenreihe des Zentrums für europäische Studien,
Jean Monnet Lehrstuhl für europäische Studien, Universität
Trier http://www.uni-trier.de/zes/bd48.html
Tausch A. (2001c) The European Union: global challenge or global governance?
14 world system hypotheses and two scenarios on the future of the Union
Band 49, Schriftenreihe des Zentrums für europäische Studien,
Jean Monnet Lehrstuhl für europäische Studien, Universität
Trier http://www.uni-trier.de/zes/bd49.html
Tausch A. (2003) (Editor) 'Three Pillars of Wisdom: A Reader on Globalization,
World Bank Pension Models and Welfare Society'. Hauppauge, New York: Nova
Science
Tausch A. and Gernot Köhler (2002) Global Keynesianism: Unequal exchange
and global exploitation. Huntington NY, Nova Science.
Tausch A. and Peter Herrmann (2002) Globalization and European Integration.
Huntington NY, Nova Science.
|